Transcript for:
Essential Microeconomics Concepts Explained

Welcome to Crash Course Economics, I'm Jacob Clifford. And I'm Adriene Hill. We've been talking a lot about macroeconomics. GDP, unemployment, fiscal and monetary policy.

That kind of thing. Now we're going to start talking about microeconomics. Microeconomics looks at individual markets and the decision making of consumers, businesses and governments.

They answer questions like, how many workers should we hire? Or is increasing minimum wage a good idea? And why is healthcare so expensive? Now you might be thinking, which is more important? Micro or macro?

The answer? It's micro. Actually, macro. They're both important. Let's start with one of the most important concepts in microeconomics, marginal analysis.

For economists, the word marginal is pretty much the same as additional. Marginal analysis looks at how individuals, businesses, and governments make decisions. Basically, they're interested in additional benefits and additional costs. Businesses do the same thing when they decide how many workers to hire.

They compare the additional revenue that an additional worker will likely generate for their company and the additional cost of hiring that worker, wages and benefits. If hiring that worker brings in more marginal revenue than marginal cost, then congratulations, someone's got a job. This also applies in the realm of how people feel about things.

Take the development of city parks. Citizens obviously get more total satisfaction from like four city parks than from only three, but that doesn't necessarily mean that the government should build four parks. Instead, the government looks at the additional benefit, or satisfaction, generated by the fourth city park, and compares that to the additional cost. And here, when we're talking about cost, we're talking about the use of city land, and the tax money spent on building the park.

If the additional benefit is higher, then they build the park. The government keeps doing this for each additional park. The benefit of the first park is higher than the additional benefit of the second park, and on and on. Eventually, the marginal benefit of another park will be less than the marginal cost.

So they stop building parks. Sure, it's nice to have lots of parks, but the difference between having 200 parks and 201 parks is pretty small. This is the law diminishing marginal utility.

By the way, when economists talk about consumers, The word utility means satisfaction, or happiness people get from consuming a good or service, or 201 parks. So you could reword this as the law of decreasing additional satisfaction. As you consume additional amounts of anything, you'll eventually get less and less additional satisfaction.

It's like how the first slice of pizza or cookie that you eat is awesome, and the second one might be even better, but eventually each additional one gives you less additional enjoyment. Economists have even made up a new word to help quantify satisfaction, called utils. Utils are like happiness points, and they're completely subjective.

So one person might get 100 oodles of satisfaction from the first slice of pizza, and another person might only get 10 oodles. So the ideas here make sense, right? But the whole numbers thing, this oodles idea, it does seem a little contrived. People don't actually make these calculations, do they?

Yeah, they do. You don't write them down or think about your happiness in terms of oodles, but you do likely unconsciously use marginal analysis every day. Let's go to the Thought Bubble.

Marginal analysis can explain all sorts of human behavior. Let's say that Stan goes to an amusement park. He's unlikely to ride the best ride in the park, the tallest roller coaster, over and over and over the entire day.

Why? Well, even if there's a one-time park admission fee and the roller coaster is free, there's still a cost. That's how long he has to wait in line.

So Stan estimates his marginal utility of riding the ride and compares that to the wait. Riding the best roller coaster might give him the highest utility of all the rides in the park, but it might not be worth waiting in a four-hour line. A smaller ride gives him less utility, but if the line is super short, he'll choose that one instead.

Even if there's no line for the large Super Awesome roller coaster, he probably won't ride it all day, because eventually, it gets old. Marginal analysis explains the behavior of consumers like Stan, but it also explains the pricing strategies of businesses. Assume instead that the roller coaster charges $5 for each ride.

Because Stan gets less and less utility each time, he might not be willing to pay full price for the third ride. The seller gets this and figures it might be better to charge Stan less for the third ride. That's why we have deals like buy two and get the third half off. The point is we all use marginal analysis when we make decisions. Thanks Thought Bubble.

So that's marginal analysis. Armed with our new knowledge, let's go back and look at the most important model in microeconomics, supply and demand on the runway. Let's use the market for strawberries. Remember, the price of strawberries is on the vertical axis, and quantity is on the horizontal axis. The demand curve for strawberries is downward sloping, showing the law of demand.

When prices are high, people don't want to buy very many, and when prices are low, people want to buy a lot. The shape of the demand curve reflects the idea of the law of diminishing marginal utility. The first pint of strawberries you buy gives you a lot of additional utility, the second one maybe not as much, and the third pint even less. And if you eat 10 pints, you're going to get sick. So as you consume more, you're willing to pay less and less.

This explains why the demand curve is downward sloping and why it's really just a marginal benefit curve. The supply curve is upward sloping, representing the law of supply. An increase in price gives producers an incentive to produce more. It turns out that supply curves are really just marginal cost curves. It represents the additional amount of resources, time, and energy that each additional pint of strawberries costs.

This graph explains why markets tend to be so efficient with our scarce resources. If strawberry producers produce too few strawberries, the marginal benefit of the last unit will be greater than the marginal cost. That's the market calling out for more strawberries.

Give us strawberries, please! If they produce too much, out here, then the marginal cost will be greater than the marginal benefit. They'd be wasting resources on things that consumers don't value. Equilibrium is efficient because the marginal benefit of the last unit consumed equals the marginal cost of that unit.

The market is making the exact amount that consumers want. This is reminiscent of an example Adam Smith used. Why are diamonds more expensive than water?

Water is absolutely crucial for keeping us alive, while diamonds do nothing except sparkle. But the price of a bottle of life-giving water is around $1.20, and that's when you're overpaying for water. the average one-carat diamond is well over $3,000. This is called the diamond water paradox, and it can be explained with marginal analysis and the law of diminishing marginal utility.

The total utility we get from water is very high, but since it's so plentiful for most people, the marginal utility is really low. If you can stay hydrated, cook, take showers, wash your clothes, and occasionally use your slip and slide, then the additional satisfaction of yet another gallon of water is small. The result is a lower price. On the other hand, diamonds are extremely scarce because they have to be extracted from expensive, dangerous mines.

Since there are relatively few diamonds, the additional satisfaction of another one is relatively high, so people are willing to pay a higher price. If diamonds fell out of the sky like water, we wouldn't get that much additional satisfaction from them, and the price would be low. It might seem irrational that society values diamonds more than water. But using marginal analysis, it sort of makes sense. Relative scarcity does contribute to a product's value.

That's partially why Action Comics No. 1, the first comic book with Superman, recently sold for over $3 million on eBay. But just because something's limited doesn't automatically make it valuable. There are plenty of other things that are scarce that we don't value as much as diamonds.

For example, panda boogers. They're super rare, but we don't put them on engagement rings or pay an outrageous price for one in mint condition. The point is, utility is subjective, and demand depends on the tastes and preferences of consumers. That's why there's no market for panda boogers. Hold on, Stan tells me that because the internet, there does seem to be a market for panda boogers.

But it's gotta be a small one. I think the example still holds up. Anyway, the demand also depends on the number of substitutes.

For example, strawberries have plenty of substitute goods. Cherries, raspberries, blueberries. When the price goes up for strawberries, consumers buy less because they'll go buy something else instead.

This is the substitution effect. And along with the law of diminishing marginal utility, it helped shape the demand curve. Let's see what this looks like in the real world. Have you ever wondered why gas stations don't have sales?

It has to do with substitutes, and what economists call elasticity of demand. Elasticity shows how sensitive quantity is to a change in price. When the price of gas goes up, people don't buy that much less gas, because they need it, and they're few close substitutes.

Now, you could walk or ride your bike or get an electric car, but there's nothing else you could put in your current gas guzzler. This goes the other direction, too. If gas stations had sales, consumers wouldn't buy that much more gas.

Economists would say that the demand for gasoline is relatively inelastic. A large percent change in the price leads to a small percent change in the quantity demanded. This is shown on the graph by making the demand curve steeper. Other products that have relatively inelastic demand include electricity, healthcare, and coffee. There's no substitute for my five cups of coffee in the morning.

And there are a few products that have perfectly inelastic demand. If the price goes up, people who can afford it will always buy the same amount. An example is insulin for diabetics, because in that case, they need it to live.

What about the demand for pizza? Well, there are many close substitutes. I could eat a burrito or a burger. I don't really need pizza.

So a small increase in the price could cause the demand to decrease a lot. For pizza, the demand curve would be more flat, showing the demand for pizza is relatively elastic. If a pizza place has a sale, a lot of customers would buy pizza instead of other substitutes, like burgers and burritos. Now, there's also elasticity of supply.

A steep curve shows a supply is relatively inelastic, so a large change in price leads to a small change in quantity. Like an airplane is difficult and time-consuming to build, so even if a buyer is willing to pay more for one, they're still going to have to wait. Relatively elastic supply is when quantity is sensitive to a change in price because producers can respond quickly.

Stuff like t-shirts and strawberries. Something like the supply for Vincent van Gogh paintings? Well, that's perfectly inelastic because when the price goes up, the quantity doesn't change.

It doesn't matter if people want more. Van Gogh is not going to be doing any more paintings. So that's microeconomics in a nutshell. It doesn't focus on GDP or unemployment. It analyzes the details.

It's helpful to understand concepts like marginal analysis and elasticity. You're going to be using them to make decisions anyway, so you might as well understand what's going on. Ideally, that'll help you make better decisions.

We hope the additional benefits of watching this video was greater than the additional costs. I'd say it was at least 50 utils for me. And not that it's a utile contest. But I'd say 55 oodles.

See you next week. Crash Course Economics is made with the help of all these nice people. If you're still watching the credits, your demand for this video is just about to outstrip the supply.

But you can create more supply when you support Crash Course at Patreon. You'll help keep Crash Course free for everyone forever and get great rewards. Thanks for watching.

I hope you got some oodles out of this.