Transcript for:
Understanding Macroeconomic Risks and Perspectives

[Music] Hello everyone. Thank you for joining us today. My  name is Behzad Mortazavi, I'm the Dean of the College   of Arts and Sciences at Syracuse University.  I want to welcome you today's- to today's Arts   and Sciences' Alumni Academy. Uh, the College of  Arts and Sciences offers these Zoom talks as a   way of letting alumni know of the great research  and scholarship being done in the College, and in   today's case, by our alumni. Today we're pleased  to present Shocks, Crises and False Alarms: How to   Assess True Macroeconomic Risk, and our presenter  today is Paul Swartz. Paul is a senior economist   and executive director of the Boston Consulting  Group Center for Macroeconomics. He graduated from   SU in 2005 with degrees in economics, accounting,  and finance. Paul serves as the chair- as the vice   chair of the College of Arts and Sciences' Dean's  Advisory Board and I've enjoyed getting to   know him in this capacity. Paul is co-author of  Shocks, Crises, and False Alarms: How to Assess True   Macroeconomic Risk. I know this book has been  a labor of love for him and I'm excited he's   here to speak to us today. His work has also been  featured in Time, The Wall Street Journal, Harvard   Business Review, the World Economic Forum, Fortune,  and others, and Paul frequently speaks about global   macroeconomic developments with leaders, investors,  and policy makers. I know we're all excited to get   to today's presentation so with that I'll turn it  over to Paul. [Paul} Thank you, Behzad. It's a great pleasure   to be with all of you, um, friends and family and uh,  fellow alumnists of- of Syracuse, and to talk- talk   about a topic that's um, quite uh, near and dear to-  to my heart: um, macroeconomics. So I'm going to show   up uh, some slides that I'm going to walk through,  uh, and for the next uh, half hour or so I'd like   to sort of hit on three major- major themes that we  we'll sort of walk across. First we'll take a tour   of uh, what has happened over the last few years  as a bit of an exercise in considering what we   all have to go through digesting the narrative of  macroeconomics. Then uh, pick up a tool set which is   really the- the- what I call the "how" of our book  um, of three good habits to try to better equip   ourselves to engage with the dialogue about the  macroeconomy. And then sort of put those tools to   the test by picking out three case studies, uh, one  which is more backwards looking, one which is more   contemporaneous, and then a third which is a bit  of a- a tactical and strategic conversation about   where we see the macroeconomy going from here.  And then there'll be some time for for Q&A. So to begin, um, I- the- the first section as- as I  said is a bit of a look back. Where have we   come from over the last few years and what have  we had to digest? So we dial the clock back to   2020. The narrative was of a great depression. Uh, even in- as- as 2020 passed and the recovery   started to take hold, stories of a next Great  Depression were commonplace. Yet despite that, uh-   the breadth, uh, speed and uh, completeness of the  recovery was overwhelming. We move on to 2021. Uh,   a new narrative take- takes hold of the return of  1970s-style inflation. Of a structural inflation   that could deliver things like stagflation,  uh, very high interest rates, uh, low asset-   asset price valuations. Um, yet what happened was  inflation soared and then came back down in a   relatively healthy way. By 2022 monetary policy  has tightened materially, in part because it-   because of this story of inflation, and a new story  has emerged: that we're on the cusp of a cascade   of defaults, particularly in the emerging market,  because higher interest rates are going to mean   sort of a series of crises as a global economy  laden down with debts is unable to- unable to   cope. But what happened was the emerging markets  actually outperformed developed markets, if I look   at- on a currency basis, because the backdrop  was different. How they'd handled um, things   from a policy perspective were different than  certainly the late 1990s. So again, a story of   doom that didn't transpire. Um, what about 2023?  The last- better part of the last two years:   a consistent story of quote unquote "inevitable  recession" was commonplace. There could be no soft   landing because there was no way to bring down  inflation without delivering recession. There'd   be no soft landing because it was not possible  to raise interest rates this quickly without   the labor market cracking. But again, it was a very  different reality. It was one of labor markets that   stayed unusually healthy um, and the unemployment  rate stayed very low despite a very meaningful   softening in um, wage growth, a very meaningful  softening in- in job openings, that allowed a soft   landing to be largely accomplished if not all the  way done. So if this is the world that we all have   to live- live through of uh- a- of an incremental  narrative that shifts from focusing on one crisis   to the next and yet consistently not delivering -  not because there aren't risks, but because it's   sort of chasing the headlines - how can we better  engage with something that matters to all of   us: the state of the economy and how it- how it  transpires? Well, our argument is: headlines aren't   going to be your friend and forecasts aren't going  to be your friend. Um, the chart on the right is- is   worth taking a little pause on just to consider  that if you said, 'okay, I understand the- the media   has- has a bias for sort of salacious- salacious  headlines, um, I need to focus on perhaps what the   professionals say,' well, the professionals on- on  Wall Street predicted a recession consistently   over the last two years, in that every quarter  was anticipated to be a sharp slowdown in growth.   Despite that, you saw consistently strong growth,  even accelerating growth, and it took almost   two years for finally those forecasts to start  to be updated. Um, so if neither of these things   can be sort of your friend, what can you do? Well,  obviously we- we think you should read the book. Um,   we think there's a much more sort of pragmatic - a  rationally optimistic take - for how to engage with   macroeconomics; that is sort of a rec- a reclaiming  of your own judgment, because these aren't sort of   precise scientific things where you need a lot of  technical expertise to deal with, you need a little   bit of contextual knowledge and then a very broad-based um, and sort of open-minded approach to apply   your judgment. So what is our- what is our sort  of suggestions? We open up the book with three   habits. Uh, first what we call "Reject Master Model  Mentality." Second: "Discounting Dooms- Doom-mongering."   And three: "Embrace Economic Eclecticism." Rejecting  master model mentality is really an argument that you   want to understand that the economic system is  so dynamic, so radically uncertain, that it will   never be predictable in a- in a- even with the most  sophisticated of models. And um, rather than sort   of anchoring on any one simple thing, or even one  very complex thing. And we like to point out that   this is not something that's been- that we're  not- we're not inventing this. Um, a litany of- of very   uh, well-known economists have argued this uh, for  a long time. Keynes said "economics is not homogenous   through time;" Von Mises said "there are no constant  relations in economics;" and Hayek said "outright error   to imitate the- it's an outright error to imitate  the successful physical sciences." Economics um, has   been sort of pulled towards a formulaic approach  and then it spills out into the public dialogue   as if- if you can tinker with a machine, when it's a  really much more complex, much less um, prescriptive   dynamic. And we like to tell a story where uh, when  Hayek won the Nobel Prize in 1974, the Nobel Prize   for Economics was a relatively new creation. And  he came and gave this- this rather amusing speech   where he said, 'well if you'd asked me, I would  have told you- you should never create this prize.   Because the prize will confer upon an economist  more authority than any economist should project.'   And I think what he really meant by this was, well,  the person who wins the Noble Prize in Physics is   not going to be asked about housing policy, or tax  policy, or uh, any other- you- or financial markets, or   interest rates. Um, but economists will be pulled  into almost every um, every discussion - for good   reasons - because their tool set is- is applicable  when thinking about tradeoffs. But to anoint them   with sort of a prestige of- of- sort of a- of- of  the Nobel laurates, Hayek was arguing a sort of a   mistake. And he said, 'okay, well maybe if -if we can't  take it away, we can- we can make them all ascribe   to an oath of humility.' Um, I don't think the oath  of humility has taken off in economics, either, but   we can be aware that when we see the prestigious  um, accolated, very smart, economist on the TV, their   knowledge is very particular or very narrow. Um,  and what they're suggesting, or the topic they're   talking about, is probably well outside of- of what  they've been sort of awarded academic honors for.   This is useful in thinking: 'okay, all of this stuff  is idiosyncratic. All of this stuff is a one round   game. And I'm in a place with- with a, you know, with  a reasonable amount of knowledge to make judgments   and sort of question this, rather than just accept  what they're saying.' Well, our second good habit is   is discounting doom-mongering. And you've already  gotten a little bit of a preview on this angle   from- from the headlines in- in- at the beginning  of our discussion. And our argument is: okay, in   reality, uh, whatever dimension we're talking about,  there's a wide distribution of potential outcomes.   But the conversation, particularly in the public  discourse and in the media, tends to live at one   end of the distribution and put an inordinate  amount of focus on what could go wrong. There's   some reason for this in the sense that you care  about the things that could go wrong more than   perhaps other pieces of the distribution, whether  you're thinking about financial markets or whether   you're thinking about sort of the- the consequences  of when things go wrong. But our argument is that   you shouldn't just focus on the possibility that  something could go wrong, but rather you should   think about what it would take for these things to  go wrong and at the same time, you should consider   the full distribution both on the upside and on  the downside to have a more balanced perspective   of risk. And it- I like the saying sort of: 'if  you're not spending at least as much time-' or, 'if   you're not spending a chunk of time considering  how everything could go right, your imagination   has been collapsed into a very narrow portion of the  distribution.' Well, both of these first two habits   are 'don'ts.' What do we suggest one should do?  And this hasn't been seated this is- this is   our argument, but in some sense this is a- this is  just an endorsement of a liberal arts education.   It's that you need to be well-grounded across  the whole bunch of things and be aware that in   any particular environment, you're going to  pull from a different set of knowledge. And   then within each environment, you understand that  it sort of works in different ways, that there's   no singular rule that it's going to work that way  all the time. Um, but a good economist is going to   be part historian, part finance strategist, part  politician, part scientist, um, part mathematician.   And it's that combination, and an awareness of  that combination, with an overdose- with a- with   an overlay, uh, a healthy overlay of humility that I  think builds up what we are trying to describe as   economic eclecticism. So how can this be applied?  How can we- how can we put this into use? Here's   where I want to take two really- two case studies  and then uh, shift into a more of a- a tactical and   strategic outlook um, in a- in a- in- in more of  an application. Um, first is a little bit of a   preview. The book is organized um, to try to give  both a conceptual overview of the "how" that we   just talked about, but also scan the landscape of  macroeconomic risk across three dimensions: the real   economy; the financial economy; and the global  economy. And this picture kind of gives a- a   a pretty- uh, pretty close approximation of- of the  chapters in the book and the types of topics that   we're- we're covering. Uh, as a first case study,  I'd like to pick from the real economy and look   at recovery dynamics. How do e- economic recoveries  work? And this really brings us back to 2020. In the depths of COVID, when everything was going wrong,  how could we look at what was going wrong   and think about what the recovery was potentially  likely to look at? A common approach um, was to look   at the unemployment rate. To say, 'like, okay this  many people have lost their jobs. This- that- that   spending power has been sort of sucked out of the  economy. Um, when unemployment rates fall, they tend   to fall in this pattern.' Um, and that sort of fueled  a rather pessimistic outlook um, even by the mid-   the middle of um, 2020, that it would be a long time  before we got back to unemployment rates similar   to what we saw at the tail end of the 2010s. Which  was suggestive of uh, very pessimistic um, prospects   that we were really going back to a repeat of a  very slack labor market, which would likely mean   uh, very modest real wage gains, and probably modest  productivity growth, all adding up to weak economic   growth. Um, not to mention that that's at a- at a-  at a person level, that means a- a lot of people   struggle to find work for a long time. Fortunately,  what actually happened was the unemployment rate   came down extremely quickly, um, and continued  to come down until you got back to something   that was very, very similar to what you had in  2019, arguably even more overheated. So what- what   went wrong from an economics profession  perspective, and how could you have looked   at this and seen something- um, something different?  Well, a very simple way of looking at this - and   we're sort of illustrating one of the 'don'ts' here  of don't- don't use the master model - but that idea   that, okay, well, unemployment- unemployment rates  give me an idea of how bad the economy is, how   bad this recession has been, and they tell me  something about how long a recovery should take.   Uh, historically the relationship is from- from  a macroeconomic perspective actually relatively   decent, and if anything, the outlier was 2008  where the recovery was unusually long relative to   uh, the peak in the unemployment rate, so there's a-  there's a question in the- in the modeler's mind of:   'does this mean very elevated unemployment rates  mean even longer um, recoveries?' Well, if we just   stretch this out and say: 'well, given the peak in  the unemployment rate in COVID, how long would it have   taken?' Um, again, sort of doing what we say you don't-  you shouldn't do, taking that master model approach,   you're talking about a 10-year recovery. And I  think that, while not in this simplified form,   that mentality fed into that expectation that  this was going to take a really long time. What   actually happened, again, was a very fast recovery  that took you back to a very tight labor market   in about a year and a half. So, what could have we  done differently? Well, instead of just looking sort   of at a- at a data first approach and you said,  'well, what is it that drives recoveries?' And - this   is our framework in- in chapter four of the book -   to say that a recovery, an economic recovery, is   really about what happens to the supply side of  the economy, what happens to the- the ingredients   of potential output: labor, capital, and productivity?  And are those impaired? And if those are impaired,   then I should expect a relatively weak recovery.  Um, but if those are not impaired, I should expect   a recovery that comes back to my pre-existing  trend uh, in reasonably short order but ultimately   back to that trend. And it's nice to use the global  financial crisis from 2008 as a case study of   testing this because you can say- you can compare  three different countries, in this case Canada, the   US, and Greece, and look at how the recovery- the  recovery looked and then consider why or where it   was coming from. Um, here we- we- you- you see Canada  looks what we call like a v-shape um, and I- and I   should pause for a moment and say, we have somewhat  of a different approach for thinking about   recoveries, because rather than talking about the  speed or the timing, which gets a lot of attention,   um, and in some sense I think is very difficult  to forecast, we think there's a lot more value in   thinking about what the ultimate recovery is, and  whether you recover to that trend, um, and we think   that's actually more forecastable, and ultimately,  more important, because that gap between the trend   and what you actually did is the ultimate um, loss  potential. So even if it's a big draw down uh, if it   recovers to that pre-existing trend, the- the total  economic loss is relatively modest. Canada had a   has a relatively v-shaped recovery in 2008. Why?  Because there's no overhang in terms of a housing   crisis that cripples household balance sheets, that  breaks the financial system, um, so they're   able to go back to this sort of old production  function in short order. In the US, household   balance sheets are crippled, small business balance  sheets are crippled, the banking system sort of uh,   uh, particularly credit intermediation um, of  non-banks, shuts down. That leads to a recovery,   but basically a shift down in potential output. A  very weak recovery in- in our lens. And then it- it   can be even worse where, if you have a- a downgrade  in uh, fiscal capacity, in the case of Greece where   you had a sovereign crisis, not only do you sort  of see a shift down in output, but you- when you   get a recovery, it's weaker than your pre-existing  growth rate. Um, and that- that's sort of the worst-   case scenario. So what did COVID look like? Well, COVID wasn't a crisis that need- necessarily needed to   leave these types of overhangs and household  balance sheets on the banking system. Um, and   for that reason, you can see if we line up uh, for  the US data here COVID and uh, the great financial   crisis, you get two very different natures of  recovery. One is essentially complete and one   is essentially, you get um, a U- shape, it's we're  fudging a little here and bending the U, but you   get a U- shape where there's a big downgrading  capacity. This was um, ultimately not really a   judgment about economics, but a judgment about  politics and political willingness and ability   to bridge the gap so that healthy households and  healthy firms would be able to restart when we got   past the the most difficult parts of the pandemic.  And that's largely what happened. We wrote about   this in- in uh, early 2020 uh, for Harvard Business  Review uh, so we like to say this was not hindsight.  Um, but I- I- I don't want to make too big of a deal  of that in the sense that economists are always   going to get it wrong. You should not anchor um,  with any extraordinarily- extraordinarily high   level of confidence that they know what's going  to happen. You should sort of pressure test whether   you think what they're saying makes sense and  have a framework to- to test it against. And that   hopefully is what we're doing in the book. Well,  the second case study I'd like to use is from   our second pillar, financial risks, and about debt. A  very popular question uh, there's too much debt. Uh,   perhaps the most popular question I get is, 'when  is this going to be a problem? When are we going   to get a crisis, particularly on the on the fiscal  side uh, with very large deficits and very large   debt levels?' So, we like to use this as an example  uh, and we use this in the book of, with every year   the indebtedness of the US government goes up and  with it interest charges on the US budget, which   in turn raises the deficit even further, sooner or later confidence in the American uh, in America   and the American dollar will be undermined and some  observers consider this practically im- imminent.   Um, all of this could have been said yesterday um,  but it was actually said in 1986. Um, the problem   with this is that debt levels themselves tell  you shockingly little about the risk that comes   from the debt, particularly sovereign debt.  Um, so obviously debt levels are much, much higher   now, both nominally and and relative to- to  incomes. So what should we be thinking about   when we consider um debt dynamics and debt risks?  Again, of course, there's no magical formula. But   there's a better framework than just thinking  about interest expense or the level of debt in   aggregate, nominally or as a percentage of income,  and we argue: think about it in the context of   what are nominal growth rates - nominal GDP growth  rates - and nominal interest rates. And if you're   living in a world where nominal growth rates are  higher than nominal interest rates, the debt is   self- financing. And what I mean by that is that  if growth - GDP - is higher than interest rates, you   could pay all of the interest expense with new  debt and the debt ratio would go down. It's a very   healthy environment um, that suggests the debt  stock pile poses relatively little risk. Now, um,   um, you don't want to take it for granted um, and  the US certainly sits in a position of unusual   strength because of its position as a- as the  reserve currency issuer uh, because of the US   Treasury being sort of the the primary asset  within the global financial system. Um, and I- I   have a paragraph in the book that I like to call  the "I'm not Dick Cheney" paragraph um, where we say   just because you- we're arguing that debt risks are  not particular elevated because debt dynamics are   not primar- problematic is not the same thing as  endorsing um, fiscal policy that's well out of   line with what a sort of a healthy uh, a healthier  fiscal policy would be in the context of a strong   economy. Um, we wrote this op ed in "The Hill" earlier  this year where we said, 'look, this potentially is   an environment where you could put the foot on  the break from a fiscal perspective and take the   foot off the break from a monetary perspective um,  and you would be just better off, stronger economy,   better fiscal position, lower interest rates, lower  mortgage rates, uh, and you'd be sort of healthier   across the board.' Obviously the politics of that  are- are challenging um, but the- the mantra of "debt   levels are high, that therefore must be a problem"  is skipping a few steps and is often used as sort   of a- a worry that um, I think a lot of people have.  So I want to spend a few- a few minutes sort of   pivoting from the book a little bit to just talk  about the general macro environment: how we see it   today, looking at it tactically, where have we come  from, how does- how was the soft landing delivered,   and conclude on a more structural outlook which I  perceive is very positive um, if very challenging   um, that I think is often overlooked. Um, so how  did we get to where we are today? Well, the last   few years, I suppose we've all heard the story  of a soft landing. This was what was underneath   the hood for the- the inevitability of recession. It  was that the the recovery from COVID had delivered a   labor market that was so strong that wage growth  was inconsistent with a 2% uh, inflation rate. And   historically speaking, you've never been able  to bring down wage growth and and job openings -   as a very elevated level of job openings which  was fueling that wage growth - without a material   increase in the unemployment rate. And whenever  you have a material increase in the unemployment   rate, nearly by definition, that's a recession.  Except in 2022/2023, we were in an remarkably   unusual environment um, where a lot of people  were coming back into the labor force, firms   were adapting to- to work with less labor, um,  the- the backlog of openings uh, was sort of   being worked through, that you were actually able  to cool the labor market - the bottom half of this   char - the job openings rate fell dramatically  and the unemployment rate has ticked up um, but   even here the tick up is is more deceiving  than it seems because it's not that there   are fewer jobs, it's that there's a lot more people  participating in the labor market. Part of this is   an immigration story. Um, but it's also a story of  very strong labor markets that are pulling people   in. Um, so even that tick up, which is- which is not  recessionary in magnitude, um, is- is better than it   seems. So, I have- I have just painted a relatively  uh, optimistic uh, or rosy picture here, and I think   it's fair for people to push back on that and say,  'well, it doesn't feel that way to me,' Well, part of   what happened, part of what we've gone through over  the last few years, was incredibly unusual because   everyone took a pay cut in real terms because  inflation was very high. The joke here is that uh,   - bear with me for an economics joke - um, a recession  is when your neighbor loses their job, a depression   is when you lose your job. What happened in 2021/  2022 was no one lost their job, but we all took a   real pay cut of- of a meaningful amount. So we were  all grumpy, but we were all willing and able to   continue to spend. Why wasn't there a recession  if the- if spending power was curtailed, or why   do I say that we were- we were willing and able to  spend? Well, because spending from a macroeconomic   perspective is not about the individual. It's  about the sum of individuals. And the number   of people who were receiving these paychecks was  growing at a prodigious rate. So, um, that covered up   - and the combination of that you see on the right - that covered up um, the effect uh, um, on- on real   uh, real spending power and basically allowed the  economy to grow in a very healthy manner. Now- now   things have shifted back. Um, the number of people  who are getting new jobs has slowed materially   but real wage growth has- has returned in a- in  a pretty significant way. So spending power has   been maintained. Spending power has- is actually in  a pretty comfortable position. Um, and that spending   power is sustainable, whereas spending power  that comes from creating new jobs is, in the   long run, not sustainable because you run out of  new people to hire. Well, again, I think people are   reasonable to push back on me and say, 'well, again  this doesn't feel that good to me. You're telling a   story that feels too uh, too positive.' And I think  there's something worthwhile here to- here to- to   clarify. Economists are kind of weird. We think  about inflation only in terms of price level ch- prices changing, so the the $10 burger which became  the $16 burger, if it stays at $16 over the coming   year, economists would say, 'well, inflation has in  improved materially, we're in a better place.' Um, I   think most- many people - reasonable people - would say,  'no, it's a $16 burger, this is still terrible.' Um, and   that distinction is, I think, in part a big part  of the frustration. We- we like to illustrate this   sometimes with uh, chicken prices and computers and  if you combine those things you get an index that   looks a lot like um, overall inflation. And to say,  'look, households have lost purchasing power with   respect to chicken and groceries, but they've  gained purchasing power with respect to other   things, um, that drives economic growth. But it's  also reasonable to think- to- to believe that that   also drives uh, sort of frustration um, amongst uh,  households. So while it's true that real spending   power is up, it's also true that it may not feel  as good as it- it seems like it should or sounds   like it should. On this slide it's another piece of  that consumer story where people have highlighted   oh, well, consumers have are starting to finally run  out, they're starting to hit a wall, we're starting   to see weakness. In the middle here, sort of fast  food was one that was pointed at uh, commonly. And   we pushed back on this and say, 'well, maybe it's not  that consumers are hitting a wall, but consumers   are just reasonable and they kind of go where  they see value.' And what you see across this is   groc- when grocery prices soared, grocery consumption  fell. Um, when fast food prices finally rose above   - on a relative basis, relative to where grocery  prices had been - that's when the weakness in fast   food started. It's more about consumers trading  off where they see relative value than it is a   signal to me about an- about a particular weakness  on the consumer side. And we complement this with   the picture on the right of saying, 'there pockets  of the economy which never saw too much inflation.   Prices, roughly speaking, were falling before COVID  struck, um, basically stayed flat and then started   to fall again, where demand has been through the  roof and then just continued to grow again, and   when prices started to fall, re-accelerated.' To me, I  view this as a story of consumers who are able to   spend. When you see weakness, it's a question about  willingness and about sectors and industries who   pushed price too far and the household sector is  going elsewhere. And that kind of reconciles uh, the   story of confidence um, the- the story of pockets of  weakness, with- with ultimately a story of continued   relatively strong growth. Ultimately, um, we're  shifting from a phase of uh, the economy where   monetary policy makers were keeping an aggressive  foot on the brake to try to slow the economy down,   to where they now feel comfortable enough that  inflation is close enough to the target that   they're going to- they're going to release the foot  on the brake. Um, I- we've all seen in the press, you   know, the Fed cut 50 basis points, um, a little bit  more than markets were expecting um, but there's   expectations for many cuts from here- here on  out. Uh, policy makers tend to view this a little   bit more slowly than markets view it. Um, this does  lead to lower rates, but there's a few things that   are worth highlighting as we wrap up this tactical  conversation. The shifts that have occurred in the   economy um, have delivered inflation that's above  the policy target. And I would argue is likely   to persist above the policy target. Not in a- in a  huge way, but there's a really material difference   between two and two and half, and one and a half and  two. When you were living below the target for much   of the 2010s, monetary policy was persistently  accommodated. Always with its foot on the gas,   always trying to get a little bit more demand  in the system. I think the shift in the economy   is likely to deliver a world where inflation is a  little bit higher - not particularly problematically   higher - but high enough that monetary policy  persistently lives with its foot on the   brake. That's a challenging world. It means higher  interest rates than we were used to in the 2010s.   That means means higher mortgage rates, it means  higher corporate borrowing rates. Um, not as high   as we've seen over the last perhaps uh, 18 months/  two years, um, but higher than- than what we got   used to in- in uh this big portion of the 2010s. Um  that's a challenge. It's challenging for firms, it's   challenging for households, but it's a reflection  of an economy that's operating- it's operating its   potential. It's a reflection of an economy that's  relatively strong. So that gives me sort of a nice   transition into what- uh, what I want to wrap up  with as a structural view of the economy. And we   like to call this a quote unquote "era of tightness."  All we mean by this: this is a very colorful chart,   but all it is is the unemployment rate relative to  a neutral level of employment. So if you're below   zero, that's quote unquote "tight" with very low  unemployment rates. Um, I- I think an I think a nice   conceptual way of thinking about a neutral level  of employment is when does- when does labor- when   does the worker have a little more ability to kind  of push for a wage increase, for- for a salary bump?   When do they feel comfortable doing that? If- if- if  people feel comfortable doing, that you're probably   living in a tight labor market. If you don't feel  comfortable about doing that, you're probably in   a slack labor environment. And for much of the  last um, 40, 50 years, we've lived in a slack labor   environment. I think firms, in some ways, have gotten  used to this and they think of firm- as- as labor   as an available and- and um, somewhat cheap input. Um, but this - I think this has changed, potentially   changed in a durable way, and it wasn't a change  that just came with COVID, this was a change that   happened before COVID, that this era of tightness  had begun. Um, you saw a little bit of an era of   tightness in the late 1990s, um, but it didn't last  as long- as- as long as one might have hoped. But   if this is where we're going to live, what does  it- what does it mean, what does it deliver? Well,   there's a few things that are happening that are  actually quite good. One: in eras of tightness you   tend to see stronger - materially stronger - real wage  gains. So it's good for consumers, good for workers,   getting a little bit a bigger piece of the pie. Um,  you also tend to see stronger capital investments   from firms. Their ability to scale their production  function with you- you know one piece of capital,   one piece of labor has been constrained on  the labor side, both because the worker isn't   available and the work is more expensive. So they  invest more on the capital side. This should drive   stronger economic growth, and really is- is a- is a  piece of the fuel to deliver stronger productivity   growth. And productivity growth is sort of the- the  magic elixir of macro. Um, that delivers higher uh,   per capita real incomes, higher real GDP growth  without uh, constraining or pushing on inflation. Um   that- that's- that's really what you'd like to see.  Um, well a lot of people say - I kind of get excited   about this and say, 'oh, yeah this must be a story of  AI - new technology that's- that's going to deliver   productivity.' And there's an element of truth to  this. Um, but here, I'm actually going to be sort   of damping expectations because if we ste- take a  step to the side and say, 'well, what is productivity   from a macroeconomic perspective?' Yes, it's fueled  by technology, it's fueled by reinventing, reorganizing,   transforming the production function, how firms  work, um, how we deliver services and goods. But   big macro productivity shifts are really about  reducing costs, not about new user experiences.   And we like to use the example of Uber and- and a  taxi ride, and say the production function of- of   transportation, the- the service of transportation,  hasn't changed in a material way. There's one car   and one driver. Sure, it's nice I can- I can pay for  it with my phone and I can- r- rather than yelling,   I can and sticking out my hand I can- I can use a  um, use an app. But that hasn't materially changed   productivity. Um, maybe marginally, around the edges,  there's a little bit better matching, um, but it's   also added a bunch of cost in terms of the- the  technology stack. Um, and why do I feel comfortable   saying there sort of no big productivity shift?  Because when you see big productivity shifts in   a sector of the economy, you see prices fall, and  there hasn't been a price fall in the service   of transportation. Sort of a curiosity: it's- it's  usually cheaper to hail a yellow cab um, but it's   just more convenient to- to pay for- pay for the  Uber. Um, what gives- and then my last point that I   want to wrap up on is I think it's fair for people  to say, 'well, this is this is a relatively nice   story, um, but why- why do you believe that an era  of tightness will- will persist?' And here's a- here's   a clarification: a recession - it ultimately will  come. I- I don't think one is likely in the near   term, um, but one will come. Uh, but it doesn't take  a normal recession to unwind or break down the era   of tightness. In the late- in the 60s, which I like  to use as an analog, there were many recessions.   But you usually find yourself back in a- in a- in an  environment where the labor market is relatively   tight, and you have real wage gains, and you have  productivity um, as you work your way through the   recession. In contrast, the eras of tightness  that we see over the last 120 years all end   when you see a particular type of- two picture-  two- two types of recession. Both I describe as   more structural in nature. These are very, very bad  recessions. Either they come from systemic banking   crises, which cripple the banking system, stop credit  intermediation, and lead to very long hangovers - uh,   the Great Depression and the Great Recession  of 2008 come- are, are the two break points in   our sample. Or, they come from a structural break  in inflation like you saw late- late 1960s, early   1970s, where inflation went up, stayed higher, fed  through to um, long-term inflation expectations   which means long-term interest rates go much  higher, and then you enter a period of stagnation   with high inflation, high unemployment rates, um,  weak productivity, weak investment um, in a- in a   variety of ways. And neither of these things- I  think the structural inflation argument um, is   not likely to come. Why? Because I think we've-  we've seen a monetary policy, we've seen the   authority of the Fed, be willing and able to  push back against inflation in a material way.   Um, it's- it's interesting to remember and note that  the largest inflation in uh, the 20th century was   after World War II. Um, I- I like to say, you know,  'no one remembers that' and usually it is tossed   back to me that yeah, no one remembers that because  we weren't alive. Um, but, uh, it's kind of forgotten   in- in the historical record because it didn't  leave a a durable macroeconomic footprint. The   1970s, while smaller in terms of annual inflation,  left a significant and damaging economic footprint.   Um, and in the case of the financial system, there's-  certainly there are risks, but there aren't things   that you can point at where you can say, 'well,  if that were to stop, we would see a material   breakdown in credit intermediation that would  lead to some sort of break in balance sheets.'   If anything, um, the- the one of the few silver  linings of of the global financial crisis and   Great Recession, was the banking system is uh, more  strongly capitalized, uh, has better funding um, and   is, is, is in a better position, not because there is  no weakness, um, but it seems much more challenging   to get sort of the systemic type of crisis that  would undermine and end uh, what we see as a very   positive uh, backdrop. So, with that, it's been- it's  been a pleasure uh, and and quite an honor to- to   speak with my fellow alumnus um, and I'd be happy to  take- to take uh, question questions and I'll- I'll   drop the slides. [Dean Mortazavi] Thank you so much, Paul. That's  a fascinating presentation. Um, with that, I'd   like to open it to questions. Um, you can enter  questions in the chat box and I'll read them   to- for Paul, or if you'd like to raise your hand,  we can call on you. Um, so um, happy to take any questions. Perhaps while the qu- go ahead. [Paul] I say, while the questions queue, I- I hung up uh, the- the   Paul- my Paul Volcker picture, which- which has  followed me around my- my career. Which I got   while I was in undergrad at Syracuse. So Syracuse-  Syracuse has followed me and is quite near   and dear to my near and dear to my heart . [Dean Mortazavi] We are so very proud of your accomplishments and- and the   great book and- and the wisdom you bring. And so  maybe, I- you know, as I think about what you were   mentioning, I do wonder um, why do these false  alarms persist in the culture and- and why is   it so hard for us to get away from them as opposed  to... You know, it seems the problem is distinguishing   genuine risk and overblown concern, but they  have an element of persistence in the culture,   so why is that? I think there's a couple- a couple-  a couple drivers here. One- one- my career started   out in the hedge fund world, I'll call the hedge  fund- all hedge- particularly macro hedge funders   are looking for the next big short. Um, they're-  they're like fascinated by when, when things go   wrong you make 10x. Um, so you're- it's not that you  necessarily want things to go wrong, but you're   fascinated by the potential for the opportunity  to be well positioned when things go wrong. So for   some players, sort of the- the- the over-focus on the  potential downside um, is- is driven by what I- I'll   call a 'financial consideration.' And then they- they  tell that story and that story gets amplified. You   know, hedge fund person X thinks there's going to  be a- I mean after the global financial crisis it   was Canadian housing was going to be the next  thing to go, and then it was China's going to   implode, and the banking system in China's going  to fall over the place. And that they sort of pop   from well, could this break or that break? And that-  that's one of many what I'll call 'underlying   seeds' which get fed into a media ecosystem which  rewards brash, outlandish, um, 'the world is going   to end.' So we- we call this in the book sort of  like the 'pass the microphone.' You- you get passed   the microphone if you're going to pound the  table and say the world is on fire and it's   about to, you- it's about to explode over here. And  the person who says, 'well, um, that- that could be   true, but I don't think that's true,' which usually  me um, either doesn't get a lot of attention or   or doesn't- doesn't really get the mic. We try  to encourage people to take that and say, 'well,   rather than tell me the probability that this  thing goes wrong, um, tell me how it goes wrong   and what are the the sort of the steps along the  way?' And- and we've often found it to be useful to   consider, well often it's the case that there's  a reaction function, particularly from the policy   side, um, which is going to step in to stop some of  these things. And ask yourself 'why wouldn't that   happen' and 'why would it be allowed or permitted or  sort of escape um, the pol- the ability of policy   makers uh, to respond to this?' And I think that  helps calibrate it. But it's, I think, it's a- it's   a media dynamic um, which we're all sort of 'news  is entertainment' um, is an affliction that- that   is- is not just related to- to macroeconomics but  certainly impacts macroeconomics. Thank you for   that. Christina is asking if there's a way for  ordinary educated person to fact check some of   these doomsday-saying articles or headlines? Or  how would you advise us to go about that? Yeah.   So I- I genuinely think that the- the macro world is  accessible. Um, and so the- the ordinary person hat   um, I think there's a sort of... you should, when you  see the uh... the- the- the famous economist on   CNN or something. One: you should keep in mind that  economics by its nature is not- not a hard science.   So what they're telling you is not the product of  special knowledge. Um, it's really the- it's really   their own judgment, which has some context to it,  but if- if you sort of educate yourself in- in an   area to it, particularly - I'm- I'm very much a fan  of history - particularly with history and you have   sort of analogies in your mind that you can bring  back and compare with - and hopefully our book does   this well, of giving you sort of frameworks to  apply drivers, rather than um, just considering   the possibility that something goes wrong - that's-  that's I think how you start to stress test um,   these types of things. But a healthy- a healthy  place to start is simply being aware that when   you hear the forecast, when you hear the sort of  the- what I'll call the 'scroll bar' along CNBC that-   that is- that is a forecast that that has no shelf  life. Um, and when they say that, they don't really   mean that as 'I- I have high confidence that this  is going to happen,' they mean it as sort of 'okay,   this is a this is my baseline that this could  happen.' And until you understand sort of how   you get there, um, you're not going to have sort  of the broader whole picture. So just discount-   start out with a healthy amount of- of skepticism  for almost- almost everything. Um, Waylan asked are you   concerned about the recent jobs report revisions  indicating not as strong of a labor market as   previously thought? Yeah, it's an interesting  question. Um, so the revisions, um, there's a few   different sources of uh, of job numbers um, from-  from the- from the US. Uh, in particular the- the   household survey, the establishment survey, and  for those who aren't familiar with this: one has   sort of an estimate of um, the-... All of them - and-  and this is another- another thing to keep in   mind - whenever you see economic statistics um, it's  not that they're made up, but there's a healthy amount   of assumptions and estimations that come in these  process- processes. These are not measurements of a   physical reality. So the US statistical agencies  are first grade, first class, really excellent at   what they do. Um, and they- the two different sources  had been showing a different picture for a long   time. One was revised down in a particularly  material way. I do not view that - even- even if   I take- if I had just seen um, the revision and  I had never seen the original number, I wouldn't   feel any differently. Um, in fact, I'm willing to  sort of venture a little bit further and say I   might even feel better, because what makes me  most nervous now or in the- with the old days   what- what kind of made you nervous was just this  persistent deceleration, and you hadn't seen it   sort of stabilize. With the revised data, yes, there  are less jobs, but I don't think the- that doesn't   feed in through sort of, okay, those jobs didn't go  away, they were never there, I just didn't measure   it correctly. But what I now see in the data is: it  sort of decelerated and started moving sideways.   Which suggests that I'm actually in a healthier  place than I otherwise would have thought. Um, and   this was really just a measurement problem, not an  economic problem. It's very easy to sort of muddle   uh, I mean, it was, you know, there's a million less  jobs. Well, no, there- there aren't a million less   jobs, I just measured it incorrectly before and now  I'm measuring it correctly. So, no, I don't- I don't-   that has not concerned me, right? Thank you. Richard  is wondering why these doom-soothing fears create   their own reality? Why- why aren't we- don't have  the counter alternatives taken hold? Yeah, so I-   I forget who said sort of the, um, you know, 'a li- a  lie can make it around the world before the truth   can put its pants on.' Um, there's something about:  it's more exciting to click on that story about   how the world is about to, you know, fall off the  edge of a cliff. Um, it's - and I'll admit, there's   there's something- there's something interesting  to it. So, and we talked about some of this is sort   of that, you know, a- a sort of business of media  thing, news is entertainment that plagues not just   economics but I- I think a much broader spectrum  of things. Um, I think the- the- the- the soothers, why   the soothers don't get the microphone, is in part a  reflection of: okay, they don't- they don't generate   the same type of- of business for the- the media  folks. And, it's harder work. Um, it's not just that   it's um, sort of news is entertainment, um, it's  it's easy to be like: 'ah, debt's high! That's gonna   be a crisis. You know, Washington is broken, that's-  fiscal problems.' It's a lot harder to think about   um, okay: debts are a challenge, uh, it's really about  interest rates and the nominal growth rate. Nominal   growth rates are driven by these factors. Interest  rates are driven by these factors. It's the   interplate of those two things. This requires work.  Um, and while I think our book is very accessible,   that's also a book that um, uh, is probably not  a beach read. You- you got to kind of sit down   with your desk and um, maybe- maybe even do some  underline- underlining. It's- it's a more thoughtful   thing. And that's- it's, you know, why do we reach  for the M&M's instead of, like, you know, the apple?   Um, it's- it's a little bit harder um, even if it- even if ultimately, I think, it's- it's healthier. Um. In a lot of the data that you showed, you  didn't um, reference the stock market or maybe   I missed it, but you didn't reference the stock  market at all, um, but yet that's what most people   are familiar with as a measure of economy. Where  does that configure into this discussion and what-   how should we be, as outsiders, reflecting  when we think about the stock market and   its role? Yeah. So most of my career has been  on- on the investing side of- of things. Um, ah...   so it's, it's interesting to put these two things  together. Um, yeah, there's certainly a connection   between the stock market and the economy. Things-  if you get a recession, almost- almost certainly   the stock market is down materially. Um, stock  market valuations are- are driven in part by   sort of the riskiness of the macroeconomy,  particularly um, what I would describe as   an anchored inflation regime where long-term  inflation expectations are well anchored. That   feeds into and leads to what I'll call 'low risk  premiums,' which is just a fancy way of saying   high equity market valuations. Um, but the linkages  are not nearly uh, as- as tight as you might first   assume. Um, let's- let's just dial back to 2022.  The equity market was down 25ish percent. Uh,   pretty big selloff. Uh, that was primarily driven  by interest rates going up very, very quickly.   Um, why did interest rates go up very, very quickly?  Because the economy was - well, it was inflation, but   it was about inflation combined with a very, very  strong economy. So there are instances when these   two things are not tightly tied. Um, and the- the  flip side of this- this equation is um, and often   a question I'll get is, well the equity market  feels a little frothy um, I usually say, 'yes, it's rich,   but there's probably a lot of good reasons that  it's rich.' Um, and then the following question is,   'well, if it, you know, if it gets sort of knocked  and- and reset, if that richness comes out, what   does that mean for the economy?' And I like to  point- like, if you think of 1987 as- as a really,   almost as- as close as you get to like a natural  experiment for the stock market and the economy,   you see basically a third of the stock market  value wiped out in a couple days. Um, the- the-   the real economy, at the headline level, this never  shows up. It just keeps plodding along. Um, under the   hood you see some sort of weakness in consumer  durable, some uh, fixed investment from- from a   firm's perspective, where you see a little bit  of hesitancy, a confidence hit, and I think that's   real. But I think it's a very nice case study  to say that wealth effects that come from the   stock market, um, even if they're very large, have  relatively modest effects on the macroeconomy.   So yeah, the macroeconomy feeds into the  stock market, not a super tight link but   there's certainly a link. The risk that  is posed by a, like say a stock market   unwind to the real economy: if that's all  that's going on, I think is relatively modest. Thank you. Well, I think we're almost out  of time, but um, uh, Christine had a very point-   um, remark which is to thank you for your earlier  shout out for liberal arts education. And- and I   think that's um, what the mission of the College of  Arts and Sciences is, and- and you've deliberately   and- and beautifully shown how, you know, it takes  just besides finance, maybe history, and economics,   and other disciplines for us to really appreciate  um, the complexity of this world and- and your uh,   example is a- is a great one as a reminder for  us and our- our students. So thank you for that.   Um, uh, let me thank you again for speaking with  us this afternoon. Um, you know, great discussion   and- and very interesting and I want to thank  everybody for joining us today. Stay tuned for   more invitations to future presentations and we  hope to see you again soon. Um, I'm going to ask   now Liz to close the Zoom meeting. Have a great  rest of your day. Thank you, Paul. [Paul] Thank you. [Music]